KNOWLEDGE is POWER / REAL NEWS is KEY
New York: Thursday, May 02, 2024
Β© 2024 U-S-NEWS.COM
Online Readers: 319
New York: Thursday, May 02, 2024
Online: 315
Join our "Free Speech Social Platform ONGO247.COM" Click Here

POLITICS: Robert Hessen RIP

πŸ”΄ Website πŸ‘‰ https://u-s-news.com/
Telegram πŸ‘‰ https://t.me/usnewscom_channel



The post Robert Hessen RIP first appeared on USSA News | The Tea Party’s Front Page.. Visit USSANews.com.

Economic and business historian Robert Hessen died on Monday, April 15 at age 87.

I wrote some reminiscences of him on my Substack site, β€œI Blog to Differ.”

Here I want to link to his 2 contributions to my Concise Encyclopedia of Economics.

One is his article β€œCorporations.” Here are two key paragraphs.

Here’s a key paragraph:

To differentiate it from a partnership, a corporation should be defined as a legal and contractual mechanism for creating and operating a business for profit, using capital from investors that will be managed on their behalf by directors and officers. To lawyers, however, the classic definition is Chief Justice John Marshall’s 1819 remark that β€œa corporation is an artificial being, invisible, intangible, and existing only in contemplation of law.”1 But Marshall’s definition is useless because it is a metaphor; it makes a corporation a judicial hallucination.

I so often hear people say that corporations are created by the state. It happens especially when I’m on talk shows dealing with callers. That’s false. I always think of how well Bob Hessen dealt with the issue in his article:

Attempts by economists to define corporations have been equally unsatisfactory. In 1917 Joseph S. Davis wrote: β€œA corporation [is] a group of individuals authorized by law to act as a unit.”2 This definition is defective because it also fits partnerships and labor unions, which are not corporations. Economist Jonathan Hughes wrote that a corporation is a β€œmultiple partnership” and that β€œthe privilege of incorporation is the gift of the state to collective business ventures.”3Economist Robert Heilbroner wrote that a corporation is β€œan entity created by the state,” granted a charter that enables it to exist β€œin its own right as a β€˜person’ created by law.”4

But charters enacted by state legislatures literally ceased to exist in the mid-nineteenth century. The actual procedure for creating a corporation consists of filing a registration document with a state official (like recording the use of a fictitious business name), and the state’s role is purely formal and automatic. To call incorporation a β€œprivilege” implies that individuals have no right to create a corporation. But why is government permission needed? Who would be wronged if businesses adopted corporate features by contract? Whose rights would be violated if a firm declared itself to be a unit for the purposes of suing and being sued or holding and conveying title to property, or that it would continue in existence despite the death or withdrawal of its officers or investors, or that its shares are freely transferable, or if it asserted limited liability for its debt obligations? (Liability for torts is a separate issue; see Hessen 1979, pp. 18–21.) If potential creditors find any of these features objectionable, they can negotiate to exclude or modify them.

His other entry in the Encyclopedia is β€œCapitalism.” It’s full of gems. Here’s the opening paragraph:

Capitalism,” a term of disparagement coined by socialists in the mid-nineteenth century, is a misnomer for β€œeconomic individualism,” which Adam Smith earlier called β€œthe obvious and simple system of natural liberty” (Wealth of Nations). Economic individualism’s basic premise is that the pursuit of self-interest and the right to own private property are morally defensible and legally legitimate. Its major corollary is that the state exists to protect individual rights. Subject to certain restrictions, individuals (alone or with others) are free to decide where to invest, what to produce or sell, and what prices to charge. There is no natural limit to the range of their efforts in terms of assets, sales, and profits; or the number of customers, employees, and investors; or whether they operate in local, regional, national, or international markets.

Here’s another great paragraph:

In early-nineteenth-century England the most visible face of capitalism was the textile factories that hired women and children. Critics (Richard Oastler and Robert Southey, among others) denounced the mill owners as heartless exploiters and described the working conditionsβ€”long hours, low pay, monotonous routineβ€”as if they were unprecedented. Believing that poverty was new, not merely more visible in crowded towns and villages, critics compared contemporary times unfavorably with earlier centuries. Their claims of increasing misery, however, were based on ignorance of how squalid life actually had been earlier. Before children began earning money working in factories, they had been sent to live in parish poorhouses; apprenticed as unpaid household servants; rented out for backbreaking agricultural labor; or became beggars, vagrants, thieves, and prostitutes. The precapitalist β€œgood old days” simply never existed (see industrial revolution and the standard of living).

And:

Despite these constraints, which worked sporadically and unpredictably, the benefits of capitalism were widely diffused. Luxuries quickly were transformed into necessities. At first, the luxuries were cheap cotton clothes, fresh meat, and white bread; then sewing machines, bicycles, sporting goods, and musical instruments; then automobiles, washing machines, clothes dryers, and refrigerators; then telephones, radios, televisions, air conditioners, and freezers; and most recently, TiVos, digital cameras, DVD players, and cell phones.

That these amenities had become available to most people did not cause capitalism’s critics to recant, or even to relent. Instead, they ingeniously reversed themselves. Marxist philosopher Herbert Marcuse proclaimed that the real evil of capitalism is prosperity, because it seduces workers away from their historic missionβ€”the revolutionary overthrow of capitalismβ€”by supplying them with cars and household appliances, which he called β€œtools of enslavement.”1 Some critics reject capitalism by extolling β€œthe simple life” and labeling prosperity mindless materialism. In the 1950s, critics such as John Kenneth Galbraith and Vance Packard attacked the legitimacy of consumer demand, asserting that if goods had to be advertised in order to sell, they could not be serving any authentic human needs.2 They charged that consumers are brainwashed by Madison Avenue and crave whatever the giant corporations choose to produce and advertise, and complained that the β€œpublic sector” is starved while frivolous private desires are being satisfied. And having seen that capitalism reduced poverty instead of intensifying it, critics such as Gar Alperovitz and Michael Harrington proclaimed equality the highest moral value, calling for higher taxes on incomes and inheritances to massively redistribute wealth, not only nationally but also internationally.3

Β 

The post Robert Hessen RIP appeared first on Econlib.

Click this link for the original source of this article.
Author: David Henderson


This content is courtesy of, and owned and copyrighted by, https://www.econlib.org and its author. This content is made available by use of the public RSS feed offered by the host site and is used for educational purposes only. If you are the author or represent the host site and would like this content removed now and in the future, please contact USSANews.com using the email address in the Contact page found in the website menu.

The post Robert Hessen RIP first appeared on USSA News | The Tea Party’s Front Page.. Visit USSANews.com.



Source link

OnGo247
New 100% Free
Social Platform
ONGO247.COM
Give it a spin!
Sign Up Today
OnGo247
New 100% Free
Social Platform
ONGO247.COM
Give it a spin!
Sign Up Today